Thursday, August 31, 2006

What is a "Land of Opportunity?"

I just heard Clive Crook on NPR describing new research that shows that by one measure, the United States falls behind Finland, Sweden and France (yes, France) as a land of opportunity. The measure? How well a parent's income predicts his or her offspring's income. Presumably, if we all started out even, if our parents didn't matter, there would be no correlation in income across generations.

But why do kids of the affluent do well in the US? Is it a Paris Hilton effect? Perhaps. If this were the whole story, then America's claim as a land of opportunity is on shaky groud. My suspicion is that things are more complicated.

I happen to live in one of the most affluent counties in the United States--Montgomery County, Maryland. The reason I live here, instead of the District of Columbia, is that the schools here are excellent. One of the reasons that the schools are excellent is that the kids in these schools are amazing. I never fail to be impressed by the work ethic of my sixteen-year olds' circle of classmates. These kids, whose parents are by and large pretty well off, will be by and large well off themselves. Their affluence will not come from clipping bond coupons with golden scissors, but rather from the fact that they will be valuable in the labor force. And as the world globalizes, people with rare skills will become more valuable, as their abilities affect more people.

Paul Krugman suggests that it is policy, rather than productivity, that has led the income distribution to become more skewed, and has reduced social mobility. One wag supported this notion by pointing out that Paul Krugman makes far more money than James Tobin ever did, even though Tobin was a greater economist.

Tobin was the better economist, but Krugman is more productive, because his ideas reach a much broader group of people--technology had enhanced Krugman's productivity and therefore his salary. People with high levels of education and unusual gifts are more valuable than they have ever been. Well educated parents have a particular incentive to make sure that their children gain both the attitudes and credentials necessary for success.

But in the end, this is unfair to those whose parents are at the bottom of the income ladder. Among other things, they cannot afford to live in those parts of metropolitan areas where the schools are excellent. Let me share something I wrote for the Congress on New Urbanism:

Urban Location and Schools

Richard K. Green

The George Washington University

Neighborhoods within cities are heterogeneous; municipalities within metropolitan area are heterogeneous too. The racial and income composition of individual neighborhoods in diverse cities is rarely similar to the composition of the cities in which they lie. For example, the average poverty rate in Washington, D.C. and its proximate counties (Arlington, Fairfax and Alexandria City, Virginia and Montgomery and Prince George’s County, Maryland) was 8.2 percent in 2000; but the rate ranged from 4.5 percent in Fairfax County to 20 percent in the District. Within the District itself, census tract level poverty rates ranged from around one percent to over 70.

The reasons for this variation are myriad. Perhaps the most important reasons for this variation have nothing directly to do with schools: the availability of affordable housing and the cost of transportation. William Alonso, in a classic paper, uses a simple theoretical model that predicts that in a world of high fixed transportation costs, the poor will settle in a city’s center. The reason: by living close to jobs, neighbors and services, the poor avoid transportation costs. In exchange, they consume little in the way of housing, and live very densely. While this leads to housing being relatively inexpensive, the cost they spend per unit of housing services they receive is high. That is, while total rent in the middle of Philadelphia is relatively inexpensive, the houses people are renting may be in disrepair—all of the rent is going to pay for location.

But it is also true that low income people may be constrained to live in urban centers because of a phenomenon William Fischel termed fiscal zoning. Local officials have an incentive to please the median voter in their communities by maximizing services relative to taxes. One tool for doing this is zoning that assures that the least expensive houses are very expensive indeed. Some communities ban apartments; others have large minimum lot size requirements. This combination creates a large per capita tax base and leads to high quality services being capitalized into property values. But it also locks low income people out.

A crude, but easy method, for demonstrating how settlement patterns have played out is to look at the household shares of single women with children and married couples with children in some cities and immediately adjacent suburbs.

Central City County Unmarried Female with Children Share Married Couple with Children Share Suburban County Unmarried Female with Children Share Married Couple with Children Share
Orleans 14.0 16.5 Jefferson 7.2 27.7
Suffolk 9.1 13.6 Middlesex 4.4 24.5
San Francisco 4.3 13.8 San Mateo 4.1 24.5
Philadelphia 9.8 16.9 Montgomery 3.1 28.0
St. Louis 12.0 12.8 St. Louis County 5.3 26.8
Denver 6.7 15.6 Jefferson 5.4 30.1

The poverty rate among married couples with children is low—around 6 percent, or about half the national rate. But the poverty rate among unmarried with children is nearly 35 percent. So the combination of urban land prices, transportation costs and fiscal zoning has led to income heterogeneity in settlement patterns.

While schools may not in themselves be the primary cause of these settlement patterns, the implications of these patterns for schools are important. The ability of low income people to choose to live in areas with good schools is limited by economic considerations apart from school, or by zoning. Conversely, families of means have the ability to choose economically feasible neighborhoods and schools jointly. Let us be clear—school choice is already available to people with money. This lesson came home to me when my family moved to metropolitan Washington; my wife and I were in the fortunate position of being able to choose the public schools our children would attend. The choice set broadened further when my children decided to attend a magnet high school outside of their local school district.

It is unfair that geography allows only some families to choose where their children go to school. Among other things, it means that almost all students at some schools come from families whose choices are limited. A large number of studies (including one by conference participant Thomas Nechyba and his Duke colleague Jacob Vignor) have demonstrated the importance of peer effects—who one goes to school with matters. Of particular interests are findings that students who go to school with peers who have a variety of abilities may perform better, controlling for average level of ability, than those who go to homogeneous schools. Economic and zoning conditions force some families to send their children to schools with students whose performance is both homogeneous and low.

An appropriate policy response to this is to decouple school choice from geography. School vouchers are one method for doing this; charter schools are another; magnet schools are a third—all are worth trying. The Experimental Housing Allowance Program demonstrated that housing vouchers were an efficient and effective method for providing low-income people with housing. The current experiments with choice and charter schools could well prove to me even more important.

Wednesday, August 30, 2006

Assessment of Education

My colleague Mary Gowan is passionate about the importance of assessment in eduction. Derek Bok, in Our Underachieving Colleges, articulates why it is important:

Although the prominent critics of undergraduate education may have an imperfect grasp of history, nothing that has been said proves that colleges are above reproach. It may well be that undergraduate education has not suffered any discernible decline in quality over the past 50 or 100 years. But is that really a satisfactory outcome? Most human enterprise improves with time and experience. That is certainly true of consumer goods, athletic performances, health care, the effectiveness of our armed forces, the speed of our transportation and communication systems, and much else. Given the vastly expanded resources colleges have acquired, thanks to growing private donations, steadily rising tuitions, and massive infusions of federal financial aid, isn't it fair to expect the quality of education to improve as well?

To be sure, the undergraduate enterprise has grown in several dimensions. Millions more students enter college today than half a century ago. Countless new buildings have been built; faculties have greatly increased in numbers; new courses of every kind fill college catalogues to overflowing. Undergraduates can now watch PowerPoint lectures, print out articles at their personal computers, and receive homework assignments via the Internet. But all these changes, however broad in scope, say very little about what is truly important. Has the quality of teaching improved? More important, are students learning more than they did in 1950? Can they write with greater style and grace? Do they speak foreign languages more fluently, read a text with greater comprehension, or analyze problems more rigorously?

The honest answer to these questions is that we do not know. In fact, we do not even have an informed guess that can command general agreement.

As we ask our students and their parents to invest more and more in higher education, we must do a better job of assessing learning. We as faculty can do this in part by giving more feedback to students; in the course of providing the feedback, we get to know better what our students know and what they don't. This has implications for how we structure instruction, about class sizes, about the use of TAs, and many other aspects of our teaching.

But this is not enough. We must develop metrics, some of which might involve testing, and some of which might not, to figure out how we are doing at our fundamental job of teaching. Any thoughts on such potential metrics are welcome.

Greenstreet Advisors' Panel on Real Estate Markets

There is a good discussion at http://www.greenstreetadvisors.com/RE_portfolio.html.

The key takeaway is that one can be bullish on Texas and Arizona as economies without being bullish on their real estate markets. Because there places have few physical or legal restrictions on development, it is just about impossible to get real land price appreciation. The reason--as soon as real estate prices rise beyond construction costs, developers will build until prices are bid back down again.

Moreover, cities in Texas and Arizona generally have flat density gradients. They were built around the automobile; as such, no one part of Phoenix or Dallas is generally any more valuable than another. There are few exceptions--the Park Cities, two small towns that are surrounded Dallas, have exceptional school and can't expand, so the value of their schools gets capitalized into land prices. And Scottsdale's natural location makes it sufficiently unusual to get a price premium. But by and large, one subdivision in most sun-belt cities is pretty much like another, and so in the absence of constraints, the opportunity for price appreciation is limited.

Tuesday, August 29, 2006

Will the Housing Slump create a recession?

NYU Professor and Guru Noriel Roubini is arguing that it will--that the housing market is about to crash (especially in coastal cities, although not in Washington, D.C.), and that the crash will lead to a recession.

Housing is manifestly cooling off; housing is also a far more powerful leading indicator of the business cycle than business investment (see my 1997 paper in Real Estate Economics for the scoop on this. Email me if you want a copy).

But my model says it hasn't cooled off enough yet to produce a recession (despite what I told my colleagues the morning--oops). According to NIPA, seasonally adjusted residential invesment is off 6.3 percent in the second quarter, and was off a total of 1.2 percent in the previous two quarters. This should shave about .6 percent off of GDP; not a nice number, but not enough in and of itself to create a recession. If housing continues to get worse (and anecdotes suggest that it might), we could well get a recession by the second quarter of next year. I will wait for the third quarter residential investment numbers to come out before saying more.

Where most affordable housing comes from--Old Houses

Sarah Kunkleman, who is Assistant Director for Communications in my school, asked me a good question today: if New Orleans were rebuilt, where would the affordable housing come from? After all, isn't old, dilapidated housing the cheap housing?

Sarah's insight is correct. A New York Times article from March 6 of this year describes work by Glaeser and Gyourko:

"In 2000, Glaeser took a sabbatical from Harvard and began to spend a few days a week in Philadelphia working with Joseph Gyourko, a real-estate economist at the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. Glaeser had already been thinking about the relationship between housing and urban poverty when one day he and Gyourko began to discuss why cities like Philadelphia and Detroit — places with poor future prospects, both economists believed — weren't doing even worse in terms of population. Why didn't everyone leave, Gyourko wondered, and go to a place like Charlotte, N.C., that had a fast-growing economy? This question addresses a puzzle of urban economics. Cities (think of Las Vegas or Phoenix) can grow at a very fast rate, exploding overnight with businesses and residents. Some can increase in population by 50 or even 60 percent in a decade. But cities lose their residents very slowly and almost never at a pace of more than 10 percent in a decade. What's more, when cities grow, they expand significantly in population, but housing prices tend to rise slowly; even as Las Vegas grew by leaps and bounds in the 1990's, for instance, the average home there cost well under $200,000. When cities decline, however, the trends get flipped around. Population diminishes slowly, but housing prices tend to drop markedly.

Glaeser and Gyourko determined that the durable nature of housing itself explains this phenomenon. People can flee, but houses can take a century or more to finally fall to pieces. "These places still exist," Glaeser says of Detroit and St. Louis, "because the housing is permanent. And if you want to understand why they're poor, it's actually also in part because the housing is permanent." For Glaeser, this is the story not only of these two places but also of Buffalo, Baltimore, Cleveland, Philadelphia and Pittsburgh — the powerhouse cities of America in 1950 that consistently and inexorably lost population over the next 50 years. It is not just that there were poor people and the jobs left and the poor people were stuck there. "Thousands of poor come to Detroit each year and live in places that are cheaper than any other place to live in part because they've got durable housing still around," Glaeser says. The net population of Detroit usually decreases each year, in other words, but the city still attracts plenty of people drawn by its extreme affordability. As Gyourko points out, in the year 2000 the median house price in Philadelphia was $59,700; in Detroit, it was $63,600. Those prices are well below the actual construction costs of the homes. "To build them new, it would cost at least $80,000," Gyourko says, "so there's no builder who would build those today. And as long as those houses remain, the people remain."

The resulting paper, "Urban Decline and Durable Housing," caused a stir among urban economists even before its publication last year. (It was initially circulated with a subtitle along the lines of "Why Does Anyone Still Live in Detroit?" until the authors, thinking it politically insensitive, removed it.) In addition to illuminating some of the forces shaping our poorest cities, the research proved to Glaeser that it is impossible to think about urban economies without thinking of urban buildings at the same time. "


Indeed, old affordable housing almost certainly kept New Orleans'population from declining more rapidly than it did. The Glaeser-Gyourko work actually is part of a long tradition of urban economics work on "filtering." Ed Olsen at the University of Virginia wrote a paper in the early 1970s called "A Competitive Theory of the Housing Market," that predicted that in general the poor would live in the center of cities, for the simple reason that they would live where the old housing was. The poor actually tend to pay more for land rent than higher income people do, because (1) they can't afford to pay for transportation, and thus need to live near jobs and services and (2) because the old housing is on the most valuable (centrally located) real estate (it doesn't look valuable because the housing stock is so poor).

This phenomenon also explains why New Orleans population will likely not return to anything like what it was a little over a year ago. The "affordable" housing cannot be replicated, and so a principal reason many people stayed in New Orleans is gone forever.

Urban Sprawl (Part 2)

Reasons 5 through 9:

V. GOVERNMENT SERVICES

Economist Charles Tiebout pioneered the idea that local units of government compete with each other for citizens. Specifically, he argued that local officials put forward packages of services in return for a given tax level, in the hope of attracting people and capital to their communities. This theory is supported by empirical evidence suggesting that people respond to service packages. Although it is often suggested that people seek to avoid taxes at all costs, work by Therese McGwire, Michael Wayselenko, and others has shown that people do prefer communities with better services, and tend to move to cities that provide the services they want at the lowest possible tax costs.
This competition puts newer cities at an advantage relative to their older counterparts. First, old cities’ infrastructures tend to be old and often inadequate, and replacing infrastructure is very expensive. Newer cities can offer better infrastructure at lower cost. Second, and perhaps more importantly, newer cities have often used land regulation to prevent the construction of low-priced housing. Old cities, on the other hand, have large amounts of old (low-priced) housing, which tends to attract low-income owners and tenants. Low-income people, who require a disproportionately large share of public services, are therefore concentrated in central cities. This concentration of individuals drawing on public resources puts central cities at a fiscal disadvantage as they try to offer “middle-class” benefits.
Newer cities, on the other hand, can provide these services at lower levels of taxes. Lower taxes attract the middle class, a migration that further increases the concentration of poverty in the older cities, which in turn worsens the older cities’ competitive position. Edward Glaeser argues that, because of this middle class exodus, higher levels of government (perhaps the federal government) should take responsibility for income redistribution and social services spending if older central cities are ever to become more competitive.
To make matters worse, older cities have often been run by politicians who are overtly hostile to private development in their jurisdictions’ central areas. This hostility stands in contrast to newer cities, which provide low tax rates on industrial parks and use tax-increment financing (TIF) to stimulate business development. Older cities are already at a fiscal disadvantage relative their less aged counterparts. But when the political class that runs an older city erects hoops (such as “pay-to-play” in Philadelphia) through which businesses must jump before they are allowed to develop, the fiscal disadvantages of the community grow even larger and harm the city and its residents.

VI. RACIAL DISCRIMINATION

Racial discrimination remains a central fact in U.S. housing markets; the statistical evidence, while in itself not conclusive, is nevertheless overwhelming. Leaving aside, for the moment, the moral repugnance of discrimination, discriminatory behavior is harmful because it generates perverse incentives, thus producing economically unappealing outcomes. One unwanted outcome is unnecessary sprawl. For example, “white flight,” by definition, requires development of land that would not be developed absent race related behavior. And while discrimination may have become a less pervasive element of individual minority group members’ treatment in the housing arena, the rising share of minorities in American society means that discrimination could become an increasingly destructive feature of the housing market in the years to come.
Consequently, one of the most important things that governments wishing to attack sprawl can do is to vigilantly and strictly enforce fair housing laws. After more than 30 years of federal fair housing laws, we still observe widespread patterns of discrimination and segregation, as numerous credible studies have shown. As time passes, it becomes clearer that testing is likely the only effective mechanism for enforcement. Testing involves sending equally financially qualified white and minority buyers and tenants into the housing market, and determining whether they are disparately treated. Disparate treatment implies discrimination, and thus is illegal. Putting widespread testing into practice is a severe and expensive means of enforcing fair housing laws, but if we, as a society, are serious about eliminating the blot of housing discrimination, we must do something serious in response.

VII. HOLDOUTS AND LAND ASSEMBLY

From at least one perspective, redeveloping at the city center always has a disadvantage relative to new development at the urban periphery: the cost of land assembly. Suppose that a company is considering where to locate a new manufacturing facility. If it can get zoning approval from the local government to develop at the periphery, then the company can negotiate an option to purchase from one landowner, typically a farmer. If the farmer will not sell at a price that is agreeable, then the developer of the facility can find another place to locate. By contrast, city centers tend to be characterized by any small parcels owned by different people. As a result, the owners of the last few parcels needed by a developer have monopoly power in setting price. Once the developer has bought the majority of parcels she needs, she may not be in a position to walk away from outrageous asking prices sought by a few holdout owners whose land is needed for the assembly to be complete. The periphery has another substantial advantage over the central city: property on the periphery is generally environmentally “clean,” while central city parcels often require costly environmental cleanups.

VIII. FEDERAL INCOME TAX POLICY

Federal tax policy has generally favored development on the periphery of cities. A striking example is the mortgage loan interest deduction (MID), which lets a household deduct home loan interest from ordinary income in determining its federal income tax liability. The MID is a residual part of the original tax laws; it was not designed to stimulate housing: the original 1913 federal income tax code allowed for deducting all consumer interest. It was the Tax Reform Act of 1986 that phased out consumer interest deductions, with one prominent exception: interest on a home mortgage loan. [Ed note: Add note here to update the state of MID.]
Yet the MID has done little to promote home ownership. The reason is that for those at the margin of home owning, the MID is not worth very much. Someone who pays little in property and state income tax might find that, even with the MID, the standard deduction is more valuable than itemization. Even for those who itemize, the MID can have little value, because the typical marginal federal income tax rate for low to moderate income families is 10 percent: each dollar paid in home mortgage loan interest is worth a mere 10 cents in tax relief. Contrast this situation with that faced by those higher up the income scale, where each dollar of deduction is worth between 25 cents and 45 cents, depending on the marginal tax rate. Of course, households with higher incomes are likely to own their homes regardless of the tax treatment of mortgage loan interest. Note that in Canada and Australia, countries without mortgage loan interest deductions, home ownership rates are quite similar to the rate in the United States.
On the other hand, the MID encourages high-income households to buy more expensive homes than they otherwise would, because the size of the implicit subsidy increases for costlier residences, up to a point (interest can be deducted only on up to $1.1 million of home loan debt). More expensive houses generally sit on larger lots than do less expensive homes. The tax code’s encouragement for buying relatively expensive houses therefore contributes to sprawl.
The tax treatment of parking had a more subtle effect. A firm on the Chicago periphery, where land was relatively cheap, could pave some acreage and provide free parking for its employees, a benefit on which users pay no income tax. Workers in the Loop, on the other hand, typically paid to park, a cost the IRS viewed as personal and therefore not deductible. (Parking in major downtown areas is uniformly expensive since the opportunity cost of land is too high to allow workers to park cheaply.) All things being equal, the suburban employee is better off. The implication was that the tax treatment of parking gives firms incentives to locate on the periphery, where land is cheap, rather than in city centers. This incentive was largely neutralized with the Tax Act of 1998, which went into effect in 1999.

IX. LAND USE REGULATION

I have already discussed how newer communities use land use regulation to prevent settlement by low income households, and how this activity contributes to sprawl. But even seemingly innocuous land use regulations can cause more land to be used than is necessary to house a given number of people. These regulations fall into a variety of categories, including setback, minimum lot size, street width, and, ironically, green space requirements. Simply put, all of these policies reduce the number of housing units that can be placed within a particular land area, in turn reducing population density, which, perforce, creates sprawl. World Bank planner Alain Bertaud has shown how seemingly small changes in these regulations can have a large impact on the number of housing units that can be fit into a particular land mass.

CONCLUSION

Sprawl has a variety of causes, some benign and others malignant. If policy makers are truly concerned about the malignant underpinnings of sprawl—discrimination, fiscal zoning, transportation that imposes social costs, federal tax policy, and regulations that needlessly consume land for residential development—then they will deal with these causes directly. Otherwise, we will know that they, and their voting constituents, are content with the way things are.

Monday, August 28, 2006

Katrina

I watched good chunks of Spike Lee's HBO film on Katrina last week. Like the rest of Lee's work, the film is brilliant, if frustratingly flawed. He is a much better polemicist than Michael Moore.

One could say all kinds of things about Katrina and the government's response to it, and many already have. I would just like to focus on the contradiction that is New Orleans. I have been there something like a half-dozen times, and I have made sure that I have gotten out of the tourist areas at least a little bit.

New Orleans is a jewel and a shame. Outside of New York, it would be hard to place a city ahead of New Orleans in terms of importance to our national culture. The city's music, literature and food make it world famous; the city's cultural greatness was underscored by Lee's inteviews with Wynton Marsalis, a force of nature of a musician who is in many ways a living embodiment of New Orleans.

But New Orleans is also a city that has been slowly dying for 100 years. Until World War II, it was the South's greatest commercial center, but it has long been eclipsed by Atlanta, Charlotte, Orlando, Miami, Houston and Dallas. The city's problems with crime and schools is well documented. The lack of progress in the rebuilding of New Orleans certainly says something about the competence of government at all levels, but it also says something about New Orleans. Three great, thriving American cities--Chicago in 1871, San Francisco in 1906 and New York in 2001--were famously traumatised. All three recovered remarkably quicky. Tokyo was leveled during World War II--and "miraculously" resumed its mantle of World's largest city.

New Orleans ceased being an economically competitive place a long time ago. This is why one of my most famous colleagues in urban economics has suggested it would be better to write a six-figure check to each victim of Katrina than it would be to spend the money necessary to rebuild New Orleans. From an economics pespective, this is surely right; from a national cultural perspecive, it is almost surely wrong.

And yet as I watched the Spike Lee film, I couldn't help but wonder whether the kids who were displaced out of New Orleans (with a high school graduation rate that barely exceeds 50 percent)into a welcoming small city in Utah weren't better off as a result. And I can't help but think about the fact that Wynton Marsalis now runs the Lincoln Center Jazz Orchestra--in New York.

Urban Sprawl

An easy culprit to pick on for some of our urban ills is sprawl. This is the beginning of something I wrote that was printed in the University of Illinois Real Estate Newsletter and in the Wharton Real Estate Review (I will post the remainder later):

NINE CAUSES OF SPRAWL
Richard K. Green


Since the late 1990s, sprawl has become a leading public policy issue. But in the debate over sprawl, few policy makers seem interested in investigating the phenomenon’s root causes. This failure is disturbing, for without understanding sprawl’s causes, politicians and planners may make policy choices that exacerbate its effects, while voters are unable to make choices among a set of alternative outcomes. The paper that follows presents nine important causes of sprawl. The list is not exhaustive, but it explains a substantial share of the suburbanization that has characterized post-World War II United States.

I. THE RENT GRADIENT

Modern urban economics has its roots in models developed by William Alonso, Edwin Mills, and Richard Muth. These models show that two key determinants of urban land values are: the value of undeveloped land at the metropolitan area edge; and the cost of transportation. Put simply, it is desirable to be near the hub of commercial activity, so people who live near job centers pay more for land and those living near the periphery pay less.
Where land is relatively expensive, it makes sense to economize its use. Therefore, building densities will be high in places with high land values. For that reason, the densest developments tend to be near city centers. Conversely, the land on cities’ peripheries is relatively inexpensive, so building densities are low. A result is that at the relatively less expensive urban periphery, each home takes up more land (houses sit on larger lots), and therefore these areas generally exhibit lower density (that is, more sprawl) than do city centers. This tendency is not necessarily a problem, because relative prices reflect the relative scarcity of resources. After all, construction components such as timber and labor are scarce resources, too. The question is whether the relative prices of land and improvements appropriately take into account all resource costs.

II. DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGES

Land use is driven partly by the composition of households. Since the end of World War II, Americans are: waiting longer to marry; more likely to divorce; having fewer children; and living much longer after their children have grown. These demographic changes have caused the average U.S. household size to fall from 3.5 persons in 1940, to 2.5 persons today. Thus, even if population had remained constant and housing density had remained unchanged, the amount of land required to house the population would have risen by 40 percent between 1940 and today.
It might be argued that smaller households could occupy smaller housing units, resulting in higher unit density. However, accomplishing this increase in density would not be easy. Consider an older house in the middle of a city. The house is in good condition, but not easy to subdivide into multiple units, so it is occupied by (on average) 2.5 people, rather than 3.5. Multifamily units would likewise be difficult, if not impossible, to resize for smaller households. Until consumer tastes change and the existing housing stock is replaced, smaller household size will not, by itself, reduce the amount of land per capita needed for housing our population. This outcome is, arguably, benign.

III. GROWING AFFLUENCE

The U.S. has become a more affluent nation. Households at all economic strata are materially better off now than they were in 1945 (or in 1965, for that matter). At the top end of the spectrum, the number of households earning in excess of $100,000 in real income has increased sixfold over the last ten years alone.
The effect that affluence has had on land use is profound from two perspectives: an income effect and a substitution effect. The income effect could be called the “George Carlin effect,” that is, as people have more money, they want more “stuff,” including larger houses and larger lots. The substitution effect chiefly concerns transportation. For example, if a large share of household income is spent on transportation, a family might want to economize, or better still avoid its cost altogether, by living in the center of a city. Conversely, as transportation becomes relatively less costly, people might seek to economize on land cost, and will therefore move to places (the suburbs or exurbs) where the per unit price of land is low.
In the context of contemporary society, transportation costs are largely fixed; while acquiring and maintaining a car are costly, the cost per mile for driving is small (though this may ultimately change as gas prices keep rising). Therefore, while transportation concerns dictate location decisions for low-earners, transportation costs are relatively unimportant for high-earners. Thus, for high-earners, who are the chief market for new suburban housing, rising affluence leads to greater land consumption.

IV. TRANSPORTATION

According to Joel Garreau’s Edge City, “the maximum desirable commute, throughout human history, regardless of transportation technology is forty-five minutes.” When people in ancient times walked to work, cities could extend only a mile or two. Omnibuses and streetcars increased this distance. With the use of private automobiles, and average driving speeds of 30 miles per hour, people today can live ten miles or more from their workplace. Garreau demonstrates that development has responded to the desired 45-minute commute by placing office space on the periphery of cities, so that commuters can avoid the density and traffic of downtowns. As a result, the amount of office space in suburbs is now generally greater than the amount in traditional downtowns, and the most common commuting pattern in America today is from suburban home to suburban office. Households’ desire to reap the private benefits of low density while avoiding lengthy commutes has pushed cities to spread out.
This result would all be ideal if households bore the full costs of their commuting. But they do not. For example, the City of Milwaukee’s Department of Administration calculates that automobiles in that city cost society about $400 apiece each year beyond what their owners pay in licensing fees and gasoline taxes. These added costs relate primarily to congestion and pollution. What is remarkable about the $400 figure is that Milwaukee has relatively little congestion, as large American cities go. In many cities, the costs are certainly much higher.
One method for making commuters pay these costs is to increase fuel taxes. For instance, someone who drives 10,000 miles per year in a car that gets 25 miles per gallon uses 400 gallons of gasoline per year. Increasing the gasoline tax by $1 per gallon would internalize the costs of congestion. But according to this argument, in places such as rural areas where congestion costs are much lower, gasoline taxes should also be lower. This would give metropolitan area residents an incentive to drive outside their cities to buy their gasoline. An important question remains as to whether people’s time is sufficiently inexpensive that it is worth their while to go out of their way to buy gas.
Other potential methods for internalizing commuting costs include highway tolls and commuter taxes. It could be argued that all such taxes have strengths and weaknesses, and that all are politically difficult to implement. But the consequences of underpricing the social cost of automobile use have also led to politically unacceptable outcomes.

Sunday, August 27, 2006

Steve Malpezzi and I wrote a Book

See http://www.urban.org/pubs/housing_primer/

Grocery Stores in the Inner City

Tim Noah's most recent Slate Column--http://www.slate.com/id/2148038/?nav=fix--is really good. But while he is surely correct that the entrepeneurial Jews, Koreans and Arabs who have run inner city bodegas are hardly exploiters getting rich off of ill-gotten booty, many poor Americans to not have access to supermarkets. Consequently, the poor pay more money for lower quality goods than their more affluent fellow-citizens. There can be no question that this is yet another unfair outcome for those Americans who already face many unfair outcomes.

But does Wal-mart make things better? I am with Noah that the jury is still out on this. Emek Basker at the University of Missouri is doing some great work on Wal-mart (http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=93768), but does not answer for me the question as to whether the prices it provides low income people makes up in a social welfare sense for the low wages it pays low income people. I do know that I have not seen convincing evidence that Wal-mart enjoys the sort of monopsony position in the labor market that would allow it to pay workers something less than their marginal product.

That said, Whole Foods, expensive as it is, may well provide low-income people with better food at lower prices than bodegas. Whole Foods usually shows up on lists of good places to work. The choice is therefore not necessarily between mom and pops and Wal-mart.

Zillow Rules

I am very fond of Zillow (www.zillow.com), a site that provides value estimates for houses around the country. It combines real estate voyeurism with lots of data and satellite maps, so I spend way more time on it than I should.

Beyond the fact that Zillow is fun, it is honest. It presents information on how accurate its estimates of home values are in a very user-friendly manner. First, it gives market statistics on accuracy at http://www.zillow.com/howto/DataCoverageZestimateAccuracy.htm. Two stats are key here--the median error Zillow makes when it estimates value, and the share of value estimates that are within 10 percent of ultimate sales price.

Second, it gives an range of estimates values for any particular house. While I have not been able to find exactly how Zillow comes up with this range, my reading between the lines suggests that it is the Zillow estimate of value plus or minus one standard deviation. What this means is there is about a two-thirds chance that a house will actually sell within the range of values reported on Zillow (if anyone has the scoop on this, please let me know).

I am reasonably sure one thing is true--more generic houses get more accurate values from Zillow than ideosyncratic houses. Have fun, and let me know what you think about how well Zillow values your house.

Was there a housing bubble? Is it deflating?

The housing market has finished a remarkable run of price increases and construction spending. Inflation-adjusted national price growth has been well above long-term trend for the past ten years, and the number of housing units built in 2005 was 1/3 higher than the number built in 2000--and we thought 2000 was a very good year.

Within the past couple of quarters, this all seems to have come to a screeching halt. According to the National Association of Realtors, the nominal median house price has been flat over the past year, meaning that in inflation-adjusted terms, prices are falling. Moreover, the median house price masks certain things--it doesn't take into account the mix of housing sold (people generally by bigger houses when prices are not rising), and doesn't take into account concessions such as free cable, closing-cost help, free cars, etc.

The question, then, is whether this means that a "bubble" has burst--that a sepculative frenzy in housing has wound or is winding down. The answer is likely "no."

A bubble implies an asset market that is out of equilibrium--that cannot be explained by fundamentals. In the case of housing, there are two basic fundamentals--rent (which is the dividend that housing pays) and the cost of capital. Even owners pay rent--they just pay it to themselves. As rents rise, so do house prices; as the cost of capital falls, house prices rise. In the vast majority of markets in the United States, it made economic sense for households to buy houses at market prices until recently; the exceptions were some places in California and Boston, about which I will say more in another post.

Two important fundamentals of changed over the past couple of years. First, mortgage interest rates have risen, and mortgage rates on adjustable rate mortgages have risen a lot. This fact by itself will depress house prices. A paper I wrote with Pat Hendershott and Dennis Capozza in the 1990s used data from 63 metropolitan areas to show that the relationship between house prices and rents is sensitive to the cost of capital. Second, planning boards have come to understand that the only way to make housing more affordable in areas with expensive land is to allow more density. We have consequently seen a boom in condominium construction. This places downward pressure on implicit rents. Hence the fundamentals have changed in a direction such that we would expect to see real house prices retreat.

The market is regulating itself somewhat already. Building permits are off 7 percent from last year, and will likely fall even further. This has serious macroeconomic consequences that I will discuss in another post. But it also is an important precurser to the housing market having a soft landing.

Saturday, August 26, 2006

Today I begin a blog on real estate and urban economics. Tomorrow I will discuss whether there was a housing bubble, and if so, whether it is bursting. I will follow with thoughts on the mortgage market, and on why some cities perform better than others. I look forward to comments.